Site icon Policy Circle

To fix the US trade deficit, fix the fundamentals

Rising US trade deficit

Tariffs may grab headlines, but the real path to reducing US trade deficit lies in fiscal discipline, export capacity, and smarter industrial strategy.

Every persistent economic imbalance carries a story. America’s trade deficit, which has endured almost uninterrupted since 1971, tells one of systemic domestic choices rather than foreign coercion. Yet, successive administrations—most notably the Trump presidency—have framed the US trade deficit as a betrayal inflicted by foreign nations and faulty trade agreements. The solution, we are told, lies in levying reciprocal tariffs. But this is an ill-fitting remedy for a misdiagnosed illness.

If the goal is to reduce US trade deficit in a sustainable and strategic manner, then the country must look inward—toward macroeconomic fundamentals, structural investments, and smarter policy design. Tariffs are a distraction. What America truly needs is a well-crafted industrial and fiscal strategy to narrow the gap between what it produces and what it consumes.

READ I China’s silent strategy against US tariff blitz

Invest in productive industrial capacity

The first and most crucial step is to expand America’s export capacity. The trade deficit exists because the United States imports more than it exports. The answer, therefore, is not to curb imports indiscriminately, but to build and export more.

This requires investment—not in legacy sectors cocooned by tariffs, but in high-potential, globally competitive industries. Take a cue from America’s own history. During and after World War II, public institutions such as the Reconstruction Finance Corporation and the US Maritime Commission built thousands of industrial plants. These investments formed the bedrock of America’s postwar manufacturing boom and export strength.

A modern version of that strategy could come in the form of an industrial finance corporation. With targeted funding, this entity could support advanced manufacturing, green energy, and high-tech exports. The energy department’s Loan Programs Office, with $400 billion in lending capacity, has already laid the groundwork. Scaling up this effort could yield exponential gains in export competitiveness.

Improve national saving and reduce fiscal deficits

The US trade deficit is, fundamentally, the flip side of its capital account surplus. In plain terms, America consumes more than it produces and finances the gap with foreign credit. In 2024, US households, firms, and the government earned $18.6 trillion and spent $19.1 trillion. The trade deficit, like a household living beyond its means, is financed by borrowing—often from abroad.

US trade deficit as % of GDP

To reduce this imbalance, the United States must increase its national saving. That means reining in fiscal deficits. An unfunded tax cut or increased spending without corresponding revenue only deepens the problem. Structural fiscal consolidation—focused on reducing government borrowing—would automatically reduce the need for capital inflows, and hence, the trade deficit.

Reform the exchange rate policy

A persistent and strong dollar makes American goods expensive abroad and imports cheap at home. While the dollar’s reserve currency status is an advantage in many respects, it also contributes to the US trade deficit.

A calibrated real depreciation of the dollar—through mechanisms such as countering foreign currency manipulation or encouraging use of alternate reserve currencies—would help reduce the deficit. A weaker dollar boosts exports and curbs imports. It is no coincidence that major trade reversals in other countries have historically followed large real exchange rate depreciations.

Yet, such a move must be handled delicately. The dollar’s role in global finance grants America geopolitical leverage and seigniorage benefits. Any strategy to weaken it must preserve this influence while enabling export growth.

Encourage saving through tax reform

Consumption taxes are widely used across the world to temper excessive consumer demand and encourage saving. The US, notably, lacks a national consumption tax. Introducing one, or at the very least restructuring the tax code to reward saving and investment over consumption, could help realign domestic behaviour.

This would not only reduce the trade deficit but also lessen the reliance on foreign borrowing. As several economists have argued, a Value Added Tax (VAT)—common in Europe and Asia—could serve both fiscal and trade objectives without distorting production.

Strengthen export infrastructure and automation

It is not enough to make goods; they must be delivered to the world efficiently. America’s export infrastructure—from ports to logistics—is outdated. The longshoremen’s union continues to resist automation at key US ports, even as competitors like China and Singapore deploy robotic systems that operate 24/7.

To compete, the United States must pair labour fairness with global productivity standards. Investment in smart ports, AI-driven logistics, and digital customs processing can cut delivery times and costs, making American exports more competitive.

Likewise, automation in manufacturing must be seen not as a threat to jobs, but as a pathway to higher productivity. In a high-wage, aging society like the US, automation is not optional—it is essential.

Rethink capital inflows and consumption-driven borrowing

Much of the capital flowing into the United States is not for investment in factories or R&D, but in Treasury bonds and speculative assets. This finance-driven model sustains the consumption binge but does little to enhance future productive capacity.

Introducing a modest tax on short-term capital inflows could discourage non-productive borrowing and reduce the current account deficit. As with any capital control, this must be calibrated to avoid panic or capital flight. But used judiciously, it can steer investment into areas that drive exports and growth.

Targeted trade promotion, not blanket tariffs

Export credit guarantees, special economic zones, and export-promotion councils are all tools that countries like South Korea, Taiwan, and even China have used to stunning effect. America must not shy away from adopting these tried-and-tested measures.

In contrast, reciprocal tariffs, like those proposed by the Trump administration, distort domestic supply chains, raise consumer prices, and invite retaliation. They also do not address the structural drivers of the trade deficit. Worse, they create an illusion of action while pushing the US further into a defensive economic posture.

US trade deficit strategy must focus on home

The US trade deficit is not a geopolitical plot. It is the product of domestic choices—excessive consumption, low saving, underinvestment in exports, and misguided fiscal priorities. Tariffs are a cosmetic fix for a structural malaise.

What the United States needs is not a wall of tariffs, but a foundation of investment. It needs less borrowing for consumption and more spending on production. It needs ports that run on algorithms, not bureaucracy. And it needs leaders who understand that wealth is built not by shielding the economy, but by competing—and winning—on the global stage.

Reducing the trade deficit is possible. But first, America must stop mistaking the symptom for the disease.

Exit mobile version